صور الصفحة
PDF
النشر الإلكتروني

of exchange seems to have been confined to foreign bills between English and foreign merchants. It was afterwards extended to domestic bills between traders, and finally to bills of all persons, whether traders or not: see Chitty on Bills, 8th ed., p. 13.

In the meantime, promissory notes had also come into use, differing herein from bills of exchange that they were not drawn upon a third party, but contained a simple promise to pay by the maker, resting, therefore, upon the security of the maker alone. They were at first made payable to bearer, but when the practice of making bills of exchange payable to order, and making them transferable by indorsement, had once become established, the practice of making promissory notes payable to order, and of transferring them by indorsement, as had been done with bills of exchange, speedily prevailed. And for some time the courts of law acted upon the usage with reference to promissory notes, as well as with reference to bills of exchange.

In 1680, in the case of Shelden v. Hentley, 2 Shower, 160, an action was brought on a note under seal by which the defendant promised to pay to bearer £100, and it was objected that the note was void because not made payable to a specific person. But it was said by the Court, "Traditio facit chartam loqui, and by the delivery he (the maker) expounds the person before meant; as when a merchant promises to pay to the bearer of the note, anyone that brings the note shall be paid." Jones, J., said that "it was the custom of merchants that made that good." In Bromwich v. Lloyd, 2 Lutw. 1582 (1697), the plaintiff declared upon the custom of merchants in London on a note for money payable on demand, and recovered; and Treby, C.J., said that "bills of exchange were originally between foreigners and merchants trading with the Eng

lish; afterwards, when such bills came to be more frequent, then they were allowed between merchants trading in England, and afterwards between any traders whatsoever, and now between any persons, whether trading or not; and, therefore, the plaintiff need not allege any custom, for now those bills were of that general use that upon ar indebitatus assumpsit they may be given in evidence upon the trial." To which Powell, J., added, "On indebitatus assumpsit for money received to the use of the plaintiff the bill may be left to the jury to determine whether it was given for value received."

In Williams v. Williams, Carth. 269 (1699), where the plaintiff brought his action as indorsee against the payee and indorser of a promissory note, declaring on the custom of merchants, it was objected on error, that the note having been made in London, the custom, if any, should have been laid as the custom of London. It was answered, "that this custom of merchants was part of the common law, and the Court would take notice of it ex officio; and, therefore, it was needless to set forth the custom specially in the declaration, but it was sufficient to say that such a person secundum usum et consuetudinem mercatorum, drew the bill." And the plaintiff had judgment.

Thus far the practice of merchants, traders, and others, of treating promissory notes, whether payable to order or bearer, on the same footing as bills of exchange had re. ceived the sanction of the Courts, but Holt having become Chief Justice, a somewhat unseemly conflict arose between him and the merchants as to the negotiability of promissory notes, whether payable to order or to bearer, the Chief Justice taking what must now be admitted to have been a narrow-minded view of the matter, setting his face strongly against the negotiability of these instruments, contrary, as we are told by authority, to the opinion of Westminster

M'CL. B E.A.—D

Hall, and in a series of successive cases, persisting in holding them not to be negotiable by indorsement or delivery. The inconvenience to trade arising therefrom led to the passing of the statute of 3 & 4 Anne c. 9, whereby promissory notes were made capable of being assigned by indorsement, or made payable to bearer, and such assignment was thus rendered valid beyond dispute or difficulty.

It is obvious from the preamble of the statute, which merely recites that "it had been held that such notes were not within the custom of merchants," that these decisions were not acceptable to the profession or the country. Nor can there be much doubt that by the usage prevalent amongst merchants, these notes had been treated as securities negotiable by the customary method of assignment as much as Bills of Exchange properly so called. The Statute of Anne may, indeed, practically speaking, be looked upon as a declaratory statute, confirming the decisions prior to the time of Lord Holt.

We now arrive at an epoch when a new form of security for money, namely, goldsmiths' or bankers' notes, came into general use. Holding them to be part of the currency of the country, as cash, Lord Mansfield and the Court of King's Bench had no difficulty in holding, in Miller v. Race, 1 Burr. 452 (1758), that the property in such a note passes, like that in cash, by delivery, and that a party taking it bona fide, and for value, is subsequently entitled to hold it against a former owner from whom it has been stolen.

In like manner it was held, in Collins v. Martin, 1 B. & P. 648 (1797), that where bills indorsed in blank had been deposited with a banker, to be received when due, and the latter had pledged them with another banker as security for a loan, the owner could not bring trover to recover. them from the holder.

Both these decisions, of course, proceeded on the ground that the property in the bank-note payable to bearer passed by delivery, that in the bill of exchange by indorsement in blank, provided the acquisition had been made bona fide.

་་

A similar question arose in Wookey v. Pole, 4 B. & Ald. 1 (1820), in respect of an exchequer bill, notoriously a security of modern growth. These securities being made in favour of blank or order, contained this clause, "If the blank is not filled up the bill will be paid to bearer." Such an exchequer bill, having been placed, without the blank being filled up, in the hands of the plaintiff's agent, had been deposited by him with the defendants, on a bona fide advance of money. It was heid by three judges of the Queen's Bench, Bayley, J., dissentieute, that an exchequer bill was a negotiable security, and judgment was therefore given for the defendants. The judgment of Holroyd, J., goes fully into the subject, pointing out the distinction between money and instruments which are the representatives of money, and other forms of property. "The Courts," he says, "have considered these instruments, either promises or orders for the payment of money, or instruments entitling the holder to a sum of money as being appendages to money, and following the nature of their principal." After referring to the authorities he proceeds: "these authorities shew that not only money itself may pass, and the right to it may arise by currency alone, but further, that these mercantile instruments, which entitle the bearer of them to money, may also pass, and the right to them may arise, in like manner, by currency or delivery. These decisions proceed upon the nature of the property (i.e. money), to which such instruments give the right, and which is in itself current, and the effect of the instruments, which either give to their holders,

merely as such, a right to receive the money, or specify them as the persons entitled to receive it."

Another very remarkable instance of the efficacy of usage is to be found in much more recent times. It is notorious that, with the exception of the Bank of England, the system of banking has recently undergone an entire change. Instead of the banker issuing his own notes. in return for the money of the customer deposited with him, he gives credit in account to the depositor, and leaves it to the latter to draw upon him, to bearer or order, by what is now called a cheque. Upon this state of things the general course of dealing between bankers and their customers has attached incidents previously unknown, and these by the decisions of the Courts have become fixed law. Thus, while an ordinary drawee, although in possession of funds of the drawer is not bound to accept unless by his own agreement or consent, the banker, if he has funds, is bound to pay on presentation of a cheque on demand. Even admission of funds is not sufficient to bind an ordinary drawee, while it is sufficient with a banker; and money deposited with a banker is not only money lent, but the banker is bound to repay it when called for by the draft of the customer (see Pott v. Clegg, 16 M. & W. 321, 1817). Besides this, a custom has grown up among bankers themselves, of marking cheques as good for the purpose of clearance, by which they become bound to one another.

Though not immediately to the presentpurpose, bills of lading may also be referred to as an instance of how general mercantile usage may give effect to a writing, which without it would have that effect at common law. It is from mercantile usage as proved in evidence, and ratified by judicial decision in the great case of Lickbarrow v. Mason, 2 T. R. 63 (1787), that the efficacy of bills of lading to pass the property in goods is derived.

« السابقةمتابعة »