صور الصفحة
PDF
النشر الإلكتروني

England Belated.

In England, however, we seem to have missed the way and are very much belated. In Queen Anne's reign, indeed, the advocates of the Religious Bank succeeded in founding a "Charitable Corporation" on the model of the Mont de Fiété, but left out the necessary State control which elsewhere had succeeded that of the Church. As a consequence, large dividends were declared from its foundation, and at length its conduct became so questionable that, on a Parliamentary enquiry, two Members of the House of Commons were expelled and many persons in high places were seriously compromised. Every attempt to found a Charitable Bank since then-and in speculative times there have been several-has not unnaturally led to the strongest opposition. The Bank of England, which possesses under its charter the power to lend money on " plate, merchandise, etc.," at one time contemplated, "for the ease of the poor, establishing a lombard (pawnshop) for small pawns at a penny a pound a month"-or 5 per cent., the rate now charged at Lyons -but nothing was done and our State Bank has contented itself with serving its richer customers only, like an ordinary private bank; while the pawnshop has become a usurious concern privately conducted but encouraged by State support.

The only mark of its benevolent origin is that the pawnbroker has formally to notify to the Overseers of the Poor his intention of setting up as usurer !

English Legislation.

The titles of the Acts which have attempted to regulate the institution are significant. Each successive piece of legislation since the "Acte againste Brokers," I Jac. I., Cap. 21, 1603, has improved the position of the pawnbroker and made the transaction harder for the pawner. The Act of 1860 increased the pawnbrokers' gains on small loans by allowing him to charge d. for the ticket. The latest is entitled the Pawnbrokers' Act, 1872, and in every sense justifies its title. It was promoted by the pawnbrokers; the witnesses examined by the Parliamentary Commission on whose report it was drafted were nearly all pawnbrokers; and the accounts submitted to it were carefully selected by pawnbrokers. By it the minimum rate of interest was raised to 25 per cent. per annum for sums below £2, a fortnight was made the shortest time for calculating interest, the period of grace for a pawner was reduced from three months to a week, and the annual cost of a licence for London was lowered to £7 10s. In New York it costs £100.

A Humiliating Comparison.

A comparison, given in London on the 26th July, 1894, of the rates of interest per cent. per annum between the London private pawnbroker and municipal institutions, on a sum of 4s. 6d. for a week -a very usual amount and length of loan-is instructive :

National Municipal Institutions.
MADRID. BRUSSELS. PARIS. BERLIN.

[blocks in formation]

Private Pawnbroker.
LONDON.
193

The Municipal Pawnshop.

The position of persons compelled to part with their personal belongings in order to avoid the workhouse has always been naturally distinguished from that of reckless or speculative borrowers. The Municipal Pawnshop, as it exists on the Continent, alleviates the hardships of this class to a large extent even where, as in Holland, Germany, Italy and Spain, the private pawnbroker or the leased pawnshop is permitted to compete with the Municipality or State, and, to a much greater degree where the community has a monopoly of pawnbroking, as in France and Belgium.

The Mont de Piete of Paris, which is administered by a public body formed on sufficiently democratic lines, may be taken in its main characteristics as a fair sample of institutions of this kind. Its operations can be divided into three classes :

1. Unprofitable advances, up to 24 francs, z.e., nearly £1.

2. Profitable or not, according to the time during which they are pledged, up to 97 francs, i.e., nearly £4.

3. Always profitable, above this amount.

In 1891 there were 1,763,695 of the first kind, 411,768 of the second and 118,327 of the third.

Since 1891 advances have been made on public securities "payable to bearer" at a low rate of interest. This enables the poorer classes to pawn their small savings in times of great need instead of parting with them outright.

In all transactions secrecy is maintained if desired.

Its success is clearly demonstrated by the gradual decrease in the rate of interest :-In 1831, 9 per cent.; 1886, 8 per cent.; 1887, 7 per cent., and now slightly under 7 per cent.; and by the fact that it has not only met expenses but has often been able to hand over a surplus to the hospitals. For instance, in 1893 it presented the hospitals of Paris with more than £14,000.

An English Precedent.

The example of nearly every European country is adopted by the British Cabinet-so far as the Crown Colony of Malta is concerned! The Governor of Malta maintains a highly successful Mont de Piété, under the direct control of the Secretary of State for the Colonies. No Cabinet has ever proposed to abandon this in favor of private usury.

Advantages.

The advantages of such an institution over the private pawnshops are obvious.

1. It is recognized and administered as part of a wise policy of public assistance to the poor. The profits made on the larger transactions enable loans to be made to the smaller borrowers at unprofitable rates, and any surplus which remains is devoted to public purposes.

2. Full reports being issued annually, its organization and very difficult functions are submitted to constant sociological and eco

nomic study, and, in consequence, are continually being tested and improved.

3. It is conducted by public officials, who are not tempted either to harbor stolen goods, or to gain an undue advantage in the disposal of forfeited pledges.

4. The most modern and scientific methods are employed in storing and disinfecting the goods received-a very important matter where large quantities of worn clothes are accumulated.

5. When necessary, it can borrow money for conducting its operations at a much lower rate of interest than any private pawnbroker, and, besides, can make a safe bank for investors.

No Reason for Delay.

On the 27th July, 1894, at the instance of Mr. Dickinson, the London County Council passed a unanimous affirmative vote for an enquiry as to how far it would be practical and advisable for the Council to establish a London system of Municipal Pawnshops, upon similar lines to those of the Mont de Piété."

Although no practical proposal has yet resulted, there can be no excuse for further delay. Pending general legislation, a clause should be inserted in the next "General Powers " Bill promoted by any town or urban district council, enabling it to establish a Municipal Pawnshop.

For further information, see the various English Statutes on the subject from 1603 to 1872; the old pamphlets in the British Museum (1680-1850) under "Pawnbroker" and "London, Pawnbroker"; "A Short Account of the Bank of England" [by M. Godfrey], 1695 (B. M. 8225.f.); "Pawnbroking" in Penny Cyclopedia, vol. xvii. (1840); articles in Journal of Royal Statistical Society, vols. iii. iv. and v., 1840-2; Report and Evidence of House of Commons Committee, 27th July 1870; F. Turner, "The Contract of Pawn" (London, 1883); A. Mercier, "Les Monts de Piété et la legislation des prêts sur gages" (Paris, 1886); A. Hardaker, "Brief History of Pawnbroking" (London, 1892); article by R. Donald, Contemporary Review, August 1894; London for 1894 and 1896; London County Council Minutes, 27th July, 1894, and 28th April, 1896; Foreign Office Report, 1894; Bulletin of the Department of Labor (Washington), March 1899; Annual Reports of Malta and of various Monts de Piété; the Pawnbrokers' Magazine (London).

FABIAN MUNICIPAL PROGRAM.

First Series (Nos. 30 to 37).—The Unearned Increment. London's Heritage in the City Guilds. Municipalization of the Gas Supply. Municipal Tramways. London's Water Tribute. Municipalization of the London Docks. The Scandal of London's Markets. A Labor Policy for Public Authorities. The 8 in a red cover for 1d. (9d. per doz.): separately 1s. per 100. Second Series (Nos. 90-97)-Municipalization of the Milk Supply. Municipal Pawnshops. Municipal Slaughterhouses. [The rest in preparation.] 6 for 1d., 1s. per 100, or 8s. 6d. per 1,000.

Printed by G. STANDRING, 7-9 Finsbury Street, E.C., and Published by the Fabian Society, 276 Strand, London, W.C.

The Fabian Municipal Program (Second Series), No. 3.

Municipal Slaughterhouses.

DECEMBER, 1899.

IT is a remarkable fact that while in most respects the sanitary code in this country is considerably in advance of those of the Continental nations, yet in the matter of meat inspection we are very far behind them.

Dr. Morison Legge, the Secretary to the Royal Commission on Tuberculosis, in his work on Public Health in European Capitals, says that in regard to meat-inspection "Great Britain is at least twenty years behind France, Germany, Belgium and Denmark."

Importance of Meat Inspection.

For the protection of public health it is of the utmost importance that all meat intended for human consumption should be examined and approved by a skilled inspector. Many diseases are caused by the consumption of unsound meat. Meat that has begun to putrefy is capable of causing acute, and often fatal, sickness and diarrhoea. Tapeworms, trichinosis, anthrax, tuberculosis and other diseases may be acquired by eating the flesh of animals that have suffered from those complaints, some of which are by no means uncommon. Tuberculosis is especially prevalent. It was found that 27 per cent. of the animals slaughtered in Saxony in 1895 were suffering from this disease. Mr. King, Veterinary Inspector to the Manchester Corporation (quoted in Legge and Sessions' Cattle Tuberculosis), states that at the slaughterhouse in that city 41 per cent. of the cows, 22 per cent. of the heifers, 25 per cent. of the bulls, and 16 per cent. of the bullocks were found to be infected with tuberculosis. It has been proved that this dreadful disease-which is responsible for one-seventh of our mortality, and last year killed 60,000 persons in England and Wales-may be acquired by eating the flesh of tuberculous animals. The Jews are required by their religious ritual to inspect meat with special care, and much is rejected by them. It is well known that they are freer from tuberculosis than their Gentile neighbors.

That this danger is real and ever present is proved by occasional disclosures concerning the seizure of tubsfull of putrid livers destined for the manufacture of sinister "breakfast delicacies," or cow-beef containing "tuberculous deposits in some places as large as a small walnut."* These casual horrors are, however, soon forgotten, and the consumption of diseased meat goes on unchecked.

*Meat Trades Journal, July 4, 1899.

How can we Protect Ourselves from Diseased Meat?

In Germany, France and most civilized countries, slaughtering takes place at stated hours in large public slaughterhouses and all the meat is examined by highly trained inspectors, nearly all of whom are qualified veterinary surgeons. In this country the animals are killed in smail private slaughterhouses, usually situated behind the butcher's shop. These slaughterhouses are very numerous. In London, for example, there were in 1897 no less than 470, and the number in smaller places is proportionally much greater; Sheffield, with a population of 356,000, contains 190 private slaughterhouses. The establishments are scattered over the town, no stated hours for slaughtering are observed, and the so-called inspectors are nearly always persons who have had no special training for their work. According to the Report of the Royal Commission on Tuberculosis: "In Battersea, for instance, four plumbers and three carpenters discharge the office of meat-inspectors; in Hackney the duties have been committed to two plumbers, one carpenter, one compositor, one bricklayer, one florist, one builder, one surveyor, and one stonemason. In Portsmouth a solitary butcher has received as colleagues three school-teachers, one medical dispenser, one carpenter, and one tram-conductor."

It is obvious that the task of efficiently inspecting a large number of scattered private slaughterhouses where slaughtering may take place at any time is one of extreme difficulty and would require a large and expensive staff of specially trained officials. But in the large municipal slaughterhouse, with slaughtering carried on at fixed hours, meat inspection becomes a comparatively simple business.

The Royal Commission on Tuberculosis reported that "the use of public slaughterhouses in populous places, to the exclusion of all private ones, is a necessary preliminary to a uniform and equitable system of meat inspection.' This, important as it is, would not be the only advantage arising from the supersession of private establishments by public slaughterhouses. There are many other

Advantages of Municipal Slaughterhouses.

Many of our private slaughterhouses are in so insanitary a condition that the meat is exposed to foul emanations from drains, decomposing blood, offal, etc. They may easily become a source of grave danger to the surrounding districts. In municipal slaughterhouses, on the other hand, the buildings are specially designed for their purpose; they are kept in good sanitary condition, and the meat is therefore not subject to deterioration. The concentration of the business of slaughtering in one large establishment removes many sources of nuisance from the neighborhood of dwelling-houses, and by placing the building near a railway station, the driving of weary and exhausted cattle through the streets would be avoided and the street danger to the public would be lessened. On humanitarian grounds the superiority of municipal slaughterhouses is obvious. The closed doors of private slaughterhouses must hide many a pitiful

« السابقةمتابعة »