صور الصفحة
PDF
النشر الإلكتروني
[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Notwithstanding a net profit of nearly three-quarters of a million sterling, the Gas Light and Coke Company raised its price in 1890 by 10 per cent., and in December, 1891 by a further 12 per cent. (from 2/6 to 3/1 per 1,000 feet), in order to pay a 12 per cent. dividend to its ordinary shareholders. This involved an additional charge upon two-thirds of London amounting to over half a million. a year. The price of gas has recently been reduced to 3/- per 1,000 feet north of the Thames and 2/2 south. The two other companies charge 2/3 and 2/6 per 1,000 feet respectively.

The differences of the price of gas in London led to the appointment of a Select Committee of the House of Commons to report as to the method in which the Metropolitan Gas Companies had exercised the powers conferred on them by Parliament. The enquiry took the form of a trial of the Gas Light and Coke Company, and after considering the evidence and "giving due weight to the reasons offered in explanation of the higher price charged for their gas," the Committee reportedt "that the affairs of the company have not been well managed. The intention of the sliding scale was to give the consumers a special interest in economical administration, while the control was left exclusively in the hands of the company. Hence there was an implied obligation on the part of the company that their affairs should be administered with due care and management. Your Committee have arrived at the conclusion that this has not been done. Hence the intention of the Parliamentary bargain, which was in effect made, has not been realized by the company and thus the benefit to the consumers, which was contemplated when the standard price was fixed nearly a quarter of a century ago, has not been obtained. Your committee think it probable that in years gone by there has been a wasteful expenditure of capital by the Gas Light and Coke Company." They recommended a revision

* House of Commons Papers, C-212, 1897; C—243, 1898; C—206, 1899.

H.C.-294, 1899.

of the sliding scale; the transfer of the southern area of the Gas Light and Coke Company to the South Metropolitan Company at a reasonable price; that the charges of all the companies for automatic meters and stoves should be regulated; that capital powers should not be granted to any company for more than five years; and that the recommendations should be enforced when any application is made by any of the companies to Parliament for the issue of new capital.

These recommendations are valuable, but do not go to the root of the question. The gas companies have no legal monopoly; and the local authority (in London the County Council) might always be granted Parliamentary powers to construct a competing supply, unless the companies consent to transfer their works on equitable terms. The London works could undoubtedly now be constructed for much less than the total capital outlay of £17,494,571; but, assuming the whole of this amount to be reimbursed to the shareholders, the interest payable by the Council would only be some £137,500 a year, as compared with three-and-a-half times that amount now paid annually to the share and bondholders. The average profit for the three years 1896-8 was £1,502,525, and the difference between this and the sum which would have been payable in interest had the London County Council owned the works amounts to £1,065,025. This sum would cover more than one-half of the expenditure of the London School Board from rates. Even if the shareholders were given £38,688,937,* which is about the present market value of their stocks, the County Council would only pay about £1,000,000 a year in interest, and thus, by its superior credit alone, could probably effect an annual saving of £500,000.

In Manchester, where the City owns the gasworks, the Corporation, besides steadily clearing off the capital cost by a sinking fund, has applied about a million of money, the profit of its gas undertaking, in aid of the permanent improvement of the town. In 1897-8 a net profit of £56,168 was made after paying interest and sinking fund, on gas supplied at 2 3 per 1,000 feet within the city. Birmingham, with gas at 2 3 per 1,000 feet, made £50,336 profit in the same way after paying interest and sinking fund on gas loans, and devoted this sum to City improvements.

In Bradford, the profits of the municipal gasworks in 1897-8 amounted to £18,346, the price of the gas being 2/3 per 1,000 feet, with discounts varying from 2 to 12 per cent. In addition, the public lamps are lighted free of charge.

Why should not London do the same as Manchester, Birmingham, Bradford, and more than two hundred other places? The profits of municipal gasworks in London, after paying interest on capital and providing for the sinking fund, could be put towards public improvements, the lighting of the streets (now paid for by the ratepayers, and amounting to a rate of twopence in the £), and the better treatment of London's ten thousand gas-stokers.

When this Tract was first issued in 1892 the market value of these Stocks was only £25,000,000.

The pecuniary profit to be made by completing the municipalization of the gas supply is, however, of less importance than obtaining complete control over this essentially public service. The thousands of gas-workers ought to be secured fair wages, proper hours of work, and adequate protection against accidents. At present but little is done to bring the comforts of gas, either for lighting or cooking, within the reach of the poor, and, even in London, only every other house has gas laid on. Little attention will be paid to lighting the poorer streets, the public stairways, or the slums and alleys of our great cities, so long as every cubic foot of gas is jealously charged for by a company more anxious about dividends than the public good. Our gas, moreover, is practically our winter sun, and no private considerations ought to be allowed to stand between us and our main source of artificial light. Whatever progress may be made with electric lighting, the use of gas for heating and cooking purposes will remain, and indeed, experts tell us the consumption of gas must inevitably increase.

Hence, INSIST ON THE MUNICIPALIZATION OF THE GAS SUPPLY.

[For exact statistics as to the gasworks in the United Kingdom, see the Annual Returns presented to Parliament by the Board of Trade, as to (1) the London Gas Companies, (2) Gasworks belonging to Public Authorities, and (3) Gasworks belonging to private capitalists.]

FABIAN MUNICIPAL PROGRAM.

First Series (Nos. 30 to 37).—The Unearned Increment. London's Heritage in the City Guilds. Municipalization of the Gas Supply. Municipal Tramways. London's Water Tribute. Municipalization of the London Docks. The Scandal of London's Markets. A Labor Policy for Public Authorities. The 8 in a red cover for 1d. (9d. per doz.): separately 1s. per 100. Second Series (Nos. go to 97).—Municipalization of the Milk Supply. Municipal Pawnshops. Municipal Slaughterhouses. Women as Councillors. [The rest in preparation.] 6 for 1d., 1s. per 100, or 8s. 6d. per 1,000.

100. Metropolitan Borough Councils: their Powers and Duties. 98. State Railways for Ireland. 88. The Growth of Monopoly in Industry. By H. W. MACROSTY. 86. Municipal Drink Traffic. 84. The Economics of Direct Employment. 77. Municipalization of Tramways. 5. Fact for Socialists. This Tract, of which 80,000 copies have been sold, has had more effect on public opinion than any other publication of the Society, except perhaps "Fabian Essays." Eighth Edition, with figures revised up to September, 1899. These Tracts are 1d. each, or 9d. a dozen.

FOR LIST OF OTHER LEAFLETS AND TRACTS APPLY TO THE FABIAN SOCIETY, 3 CLEMENT'S INN, STRAND, LONDON, W.C.

Printed by GEORGE STANDRING, 7 and 9 Finsbury-street, London, E.C.; and Published by the FABIAN SOCIETY, 3 Clement's Inn, Strand, London, W.C.

The Fabian Municipal Program, No. 7.

The Scandal of

London's Markets.

For market accommodation the greatest city in the world has to depend on two unrepresentative and sectional public authorities, two philanthropists, and two private monopolists, feebly supplemented by a few insignificant so-called "street markets." The City Corporation provides and controls eight markets, through which passes practically the whole meat and poultry supply, and nearly all the fish. The "Trustees of the Borough Market," appointed by the Vestry of St. Saviour, Southwark, obtain a large income from London's main potato market. The Baroness Burdett-Coutts and Mr. Plimsoll have attempted to provide markets at Bethnal Green and Walworth respectively. But the Duke of Bedford is still allowed to take the tolls of London's chief vegetable, fruit and flower market at Covent Garden, which was established in 1661, whilst Sir Julian Goldsmid, M.P., and the Scott family, are the proprietors of Spitalfields Market, established in 1682. These proprietors enjoy legal power to prevent any other market being established within seven miles if it diminishes their profits; and they derive their "rights" from charters of King Charles II.

The London Riverside Fish Company, Limited, has an abortive attempt at a fish market at Shadwell; and the Great Northern Railway Company runs a potato "depôt" at King's Cross. The Whitechapel and Cumberland (Osnaburgh Street) Hay Markets are dwindling remnants; Oxford Market has become a block of middle-class flats; whilst Newport Market and Clare Market are little more than squalid historical relics. For decent market accommodation we must go to Leeds or Bradford or to the Paris" Halles."

Nevertheless, nearly four millions sterling has probably been already expended in attempting to supply London with markets; and at least £275,000 is annually levied for market tolls, dues, rents, stallages, fees, &c., upon London's food supply. The cost of carrying on the markets is much less than half that amount; and the balance yields about four per cent. on the total capital outlay.

The Corporation of the City is the largest owner of London's market property, levying an annual market revenue of about £217,000 against an expenditure of some £95,000 and a payment of £96,000 for interest on market debt. The parish of St. Saviour, Southwark, absorbs a net annual income of over £7,000 from the Borough Market, which is virtually a subsidy levied on London's potato supply in aid of the local rates, and so of the local landlords.

Out of the total, moreover, the Duke of Bedford draws at least £15,000 a year from Covent Garden; and Sir Julian Goldsmid, M.P., a clear £5,000 a year net rental from his monopoly of the right to hold a market by Spital Church. This is an utterly unjustifiable tax on the food of the people.

charter or enactment, but by an old inference of the common law. What Charles II. gave to the Duke of Bedford's ancestor and Sir Julian Goldsmid's predecessor was merely the permission to hold a market: it is the lawyers who invented the doctrine that such a permission implies the prohibition of competing markets within about six miles and two-thirds. (See the latest case, Great Eastern Railway versus Horner, in which the proposed Shoreditch Market was stopped by the owners and lessee of Spitalfields Market). Now, whatever our respect for "private property," no man can possess a vested interest in the continuance of a bad law; and no farthing of compensation must be paid for the extinction of this market monopoly.

PARTICULARS OF LONDON'S MARKETS.

(See evidence in First Report of Royal Commission on Market Rights and Tolls, Vol. II., c.—5550-1.

Price 3/4.)

[blocks in formation]

London Central Meat, &c. City Corporation 1,384,000

[blocks in formation]

(Opened 1875)

London Central Fish, &c.

[blocks in formation]

(Opened 1886)

Farringdon

Do.

150,000

2,099

1,302

...

Smithfield Hay

[blocks in formation]

Metropolitan Cattle (Is

[blocks in formation]

61 21,598 16 642

[merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small]
[blocks in formation]

...

...

[blocks in formation]
[blocks in formation]

(Opened 1869)

[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][merged small]

As estimated by the Duke's Agent, excluding the value of the Land.
As estimated by the Lessee, including the increase derived from enlargement, &c.

« السابقةمتابعة »